In economics, utility refers to the satisfaction levels consumers receive from buying and using a product or service. According to utility theory, people make purchase decisions based on the degree of satisfaction they get from an item or service. That is why goods with higher utility are prioritized higher in a person’s budget. Understanding what utility is can also provide insight into what drives demand and prices.
The Definition of Utility in Economics
Nathan Paulus
Director of Content Marketing, MoneyGeek
Nathan Paulus is the Head of Content Marketing at MoneyGeek, with nearly 10 years of experience researching and creating content related to personal finance and financial literacy. Paulus has a bachelor's degree in English from the University of St. Thomas, Houston. He enjoys helping people from all walks of life build stronger financial foundations.
Nick Mishkin
Data Scientist & Business Reporter
Nick Mishkin is a data scientist specializing in applying behavioral science to business communication. He has worked with companies across multiple industries — from music to advertising, SaaS technology and information technology. He is an expert reviewer for MoneyGeek. Mishkin earned his bachelor’s degree in economics from the University of Pennsylvania and his master's degree in behavioral economics, *magna cum laude*, at Reichman University in Israel.
MoneyGeek is dedicated to providing trustworthy information to help you make informed financial decisions. Each article is edited, fact-checked and reviewed by industry professionals to ensure quality and accuracy.
Editorial Policy and StandardsUpdated: September 28, 2024
Featured Experts:
Kortney Ziegler, PhD
Founder and CEO at WellMoney.com
Dr. Kortney Ziegler is the founder and CEO of Well-Money.com, a platform designed to help people get out of debt and stay out of debt through the powerful force of community partnership. He is also a Stanford University Humanities Fellow (<a href=" https://ccsre.stanford.edu/people/dr-kortney-ziegler" target="_blank">Center for Comparative Studies in Race and Ethnicity</a>). He also founded Fast Company's innovative and award-winning company, <a href=" https://www.fastcompany.com/company/appolition" target="_blank">Appolition</a>, aimed at alleviating the burdens of the cash bail system on marginalized communities. He is Northwest Universities' first doctoral candidate in African American diaspora studies. He is a tireless voice for financial education, inclusion and re-thinking oppressive financial lending practices in the U.S.
Nick Mishkin
Data Scientist & Business Reporter
Nick Mishkin is a data scientist specializing in applying behavioral science to business communication. He has worked with companies across multiple industries — from music to advertising, SaaS technology and information technology. He is an expert reviewer for MoneyGeek. Mishkin earned his bachelor’s degree in economics from the University of Pennsylvania and his master's degree in behavioral economics, *magna cum laude*, at Reichman University in Israel.
Douglas E. Noll
Adjunct Faculty Member at Pepperdine University School of Law Straus Institute of Dispute Resolution
Douglas E. Noll, JD, MA, is a lawyer turned peacemaker, an author of four books and a graduate professor at Pepperdine University School of Law Straus Institute of Dispute Resolution. Noll teaches on the subject of decision-making under stress and uncertainty. As a mediator, Noll helps people decide between the least worst choices in intense and intractable conflicts.
Margaret J. King
Cultural Analyst and Director at The Center for Cultural Studies & Analysis
Margaret J. King, Ph.D., is a cultural analyst and director at The Center for Cultural Studies & Analysis, a research institute with a mission to understand how people find and recognize the value in services and products. She is nationally recognized for her work on culture and consumer behavior, focusing on museums, the arts, theme parks, cross-cultural issues, marketing and decision-making. Her work has been featured in hundreds of publications over the years.
Steven Carnovale, PhD
Associate Professor of Supply Chain Management at Florida Atlantic University
Dr. Carnovale is an Associate Professor of Supply Chain Management at the College of Business at Florida Atlantic University and Co-Editor-in-Chief of the Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management. He is a supply chain strategist specializing in interfirm networks, risk management and global sourcing/production networks with a specific focus on equity-based partnerships. Dr. Carnovale earned his B.S. and Ph.D. degrees at Rutgers University, specializing in Supply Chain Management and Marketing Sciences. He is a frequent speaker at both academic and professional supply chain meetings on topics related to supply networks & analytics, with a specific focus on how firms can use these concepts to generate enhanced visibility and financial performance within their supply chains and extended enterprises.
Jay Walker, PhD
Associate Professor of Economics at Old Dominion University
Jay received his B.S. in Economics and Finance from Arkansas Tech University and a MBA from the University of Mississippi. For five years after receiving his MBA he worked professionally as an analyst in the insurance and retail industries. Following the receipt of a PhD in Economics from the University of Memphis in 2012 he spent five years in western New York state at Niagara University prior to joining Old Dominion University in Fall 2017.
Derek Stimel, Ph.D.
Associate Professor of Teaching Economics at the University of California, Davis
Dr. Stimel is an assistant professor of Teaching Economics at the University of California, Davis. He has expertise in macroeconomics and finance and routinely teaches courses in money and banking, financial economics, and macroeconomics.
Beverly Mendoza, PhD
Assistant Professor of Economics and Finance at Stephen F. Austin State University
Dr. Beverly Mendoza is an Assistant Professor of Economics and Finance at Stephen F Austin State University. She completed her Ph.D. at Indiana University in 2019 and undergraduate studies at Texas Tech University in 2013. Her research interests lie in International Trade, which include firm export behavior and trade policies. Beverly has published her solo-authored paper titled, “Experience and Market Signals in Export Entry Decisions,” in the World Economy. She has also presented her research in several conferences such as the annual Southern Economic meetings and Midwest Trade.
Yao (Henry) Jin, Ph.D.
Associate Professor of Management at Farmer School of Business, Miami University
Yao "Henry" Jin received his Ph.D. from the Sam M. Walton College of Business at the University of Arkansas. Drawing on his retail industry experience, his main research interest focuses on retail supply chain and operations concerning issues related to collaboration and demand planning. He has published his research in journals such as the Journal of Operations Management, Journal of Retailing, and Journal of Business Logistics, among others. Currently, he is working on projects regarding counterfeit products and service failures in omni-channel retailing.
Amanda S. King
Professor of Economics at Georgia Southern University
Amanda King, Ph.D., professor of economics, has taught at Georgia Southern University since 2002. King’s research interests include the impact of critical and user reviews on experience goods, the decision between using debit and credit cards, and the effects of credit cards on money demand. She teaches in the online Masters of Science in Applied Economics program as well as teaching introductory and intermediate macroeconomics and money and banking.
Chintamani Jog, PhD
Associate Professor of Economics at University of Central Oklahoma
Dr. Jog earned his Ph.D. in Economics from the University of Oklahoma. Prior to joining UCO, Dr. Jog taught in the Meinders School of Business at Oklahoma City University. He is a member of the American Economic Association and Omicron Delta Epsilon. His research interests include behavioral economics, industrial organization and experimental economics.
Max Gillman
Friedrich A. Hayek Professor of Economic History at the University of Missouri – St. Louis
Max Gillman is an F. A. Hayek Professor of Economic History at the University of Missouri – St. Louis. His research includes monetary economics, macroeconomics, public finance, asset pricing and development. He is the associate editor of Economic Modeling. Gillman's books include The Spectre of Price Inflation (Dec. 2022, Agenda Publishing; 2023, Columbia University Press). He was also the editor of Robert E. Lucas, Jr., Collected Papers on Monetary Theory (Harvard University Press, 2013) and the author of Advanced Modern Macroeconomics: Analysis and Application (Pearson, 2011). Recently serving as a visiting scholar at the Bank of Finland (May 2022) and upcoming as a senior researcher at the Corvinus Institute of Advanced Studies (Budapest, 2023), Gillman has published in the Journal of Monetary Economics, Review of Finance, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Economic Journal, Journal of Human Capital, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Review of Economic Dynamics, Journal of International Money and Finance, and many other journals. Previously, he served as a Professor of Economics at Cardiff Business School and Central European University.
Kislaya Prasad, Ph.D.
Research Professor at the Robert H. Smith School of Business, University of Maryland
Prasad is a Research Professor at the Robert H. Smith School of Business, University of Maryland. He is the Academic Director of the Center for Global Business, which is a Title VI Center supported by the US Department of Education. He conducts research on economic theory and policy. In addition to many research articles, he has published numerous opinion pieces on topics related to international business and technology policy. He teaches courses on microeconomics, data analysis, and machine learning.
John Hilston
Professor of Economics and History at Eastern Florida State College
Professor John Hilston teaches Economics and American History at Eastern Florida State College on the Palm Bay Campus.
Nathan Paulus
Director of Content Marketing, MoneyGeek
Nathan Paulus is the Head of Content Marketing at MoneyGeek, with nearly 10 years of experience researching and creating content related to personal finance and financial literacy. Paulus has a bachelor's degree in English from the University of St. Thomas, Houston. He enjoys helping people from all walks of life build stronger financial foundations.
Nick Mishkin
Data Scientist & Business Reporter
Nick Mishkin is a data scientist specializing in applying behavioral science to business communication. He has worked with companies across multiple industries — from music to advertising, SaaS technology and information technology. He is an expert reviewer for MoneyGeek. Mishkin earned his bachelor’s degree in economics from the University of Pennsylvania and his master's degree in behavioral economics, *magna cum laude*, at Reichman University in Israel.
MoneyGeek is dedicated to providing trustworthy information to help you make informed financial decisions. Each article is edited, fact-checked and reviewed by industry professionals to ensure quality and accuracy.
Editorial Policy and StandardsUpdated: September 28, 2024
Advertising & Editorial Disclosure
What Is Utility?
Utility's Impact on Consumers and Economics
Utility is an aspect of economics that offers better understanding of consumer preference and subsequently, market demand.
Utility measures consumer satisfaction from a product or service.
Utility theory, introduced by Daniel Bernoulli, argues that the level of satisfaction a buyer receives from using a product or service impacts their purchasing decisions.
Understanding the concept of utility can provide insight into what drives demand, which may affect the cost of a product or service.
There are four types of utility: form, time, space and service. The impact of each of these will depend on the person.
The Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility states, "the level of satisfaction decreases for every additional unit of a product or service consumed."
History of Utility
In the mid-17th century, the maximization of expected value was introduced. This theory states that an item’s expected value is based on the sum of the product of probability, as well as the value of its consequences. However, conflicting prescriptions for certain situations arose. Mathematician Daniel Bernoulli then proposed the concept of utility. He argued that an item’s value is not determined by its price but by its utility, and that utility is what affects consumers’ purchasing decisions. Utility in economics can also impact market demand, which can affect product or service prices.
4 Types of Utility
One of behavioral economics concepts is utility and refers to the perceived value that consumers receive when they buy a product or service. Generally, there are four types of utility, including form, time, space and service. While each of them can significantly affect decision-making, the level of impact of these utilities on purchasing decisions varies by individual.
Type | Description |
---|---|
Form Utility | Form utility refers to how a product or service meets consumers' needs. For instance, a company's product has features and benefits that correspond to the needs and wants of its target audience. In short, the development of a product is based on consumer preferences. |
Time Utility | Time utility is the availability of a product or service when consumers need or want it. The easier it is to acquire a product or service, the higher the perceived time utility. A good example of this is the availability of umbrellas during the rainy season. |
Space Utility | Space utility, commonly referred to as place utility, involves the changing of locations. It is when a product or service is transferred from a place where it has a low level of utility and made more accessible to an area with higher utility. |
Service Utility | Service utility can be defined as an activity conducted to provide satisfaction. It can be best described by utility created by various professionals rendering personal services to clients. |
Understanding Utility Function and Its Application
Utility function is the measurement of consumer preferences. There are two ways to rank preferences. The first is by assigning numerical values to items and determining which has a higher utility based on the numbers. For instance, product X has higher utility than product Y. That means consumers prefer product X over product Y. Utility function assigns a higher value to the more preferred item.
The second method is to rank products or services based on preference. This may include assessing what is being offered to the consumer and determining if it has a higher utility because consumers prefer what it offers them versus what it costs.
Under utility theory, one can assume that consumers behave and act as if they are assigning implicit values to products.
Examples of Utility Function
Imagine you are shopping around for car insurance. After careful consideration, you have narrowed your choices to two insurance providers. Both companies offer nearly identical policies. However, the second one provides free roadside assistance service. Because of this, it has higher premium rates than the first one. You can see there is an exchange or trade-off here: would you want to have lower premium rates in exchange for roadside assistance? This is an example of numerical values impacting utility function.
Another example is when you go out for a meal at a restaurant. Of all the menu items, two dishes catch your attention. One is a pasta dish and the other is pizza. Realizing that you will enjoy the pizza more, you decide to order it. This is an example of how preference can impact utility function.
Can Utility be Measured? Cardinal vs. Ordinal Approaches of Utility
Utility function is a way to determine the desirability of products or services. However, there is some debate on whether it is possible to measure utility or not. One can argue that you cannot assign true numerical values to the level of satisfaction of consumers based on their preference. That said, assigning numbers to utility can help track spending patterns and market movements.
To better understand utility in economics, it is important to know the two approaches in economics — ordinal and cardinal.
Key Differences Between Cardinal and Ordinal Utility
Utility highlights the relationship between consumer behavior and demand. It showcases how consumers allocate money to available products or services to achieve utility maximization. For example, as a rational consumer, purchases are made by considering how much satisfaction will be obtained from the item or service.
In order to understand satisfaction levels, the cardinal and ordinal utility theories are used. MoneyGeek breaks down the key differences in the table below.
Key Differences
Cardinal Utility
- Cardinal utility measures consumer preference by looking at assigned numerical value. At the same time, it evaluates how much more one item ranks above another.
- Customer satisfaction derived from the consumption of goods and services can be given numerical values.
- Cardinal utility assumes that satisfaction is derived through the consumption of one product at a time.
- Cardinal utility is quantitative. It measures satisfaction by assigning numbers using the unit "util". Thus, allowing mathematical calculations.
Ordinal Utility
- Ordinal utility focuses on how consumers rank goods and services. It simply looks at the order of ranking.
- Consumer satisfaction from consuming goods and services is measurable by a ranking system.
- Ordinal utility assumes that satisfaction can be determined by consuming a combination of products and services (bundles), which will be ranked based on preference.
- Ordinal utility is qualitative. Consumers can rank goods or services based on usefulness and satisfaction.
What Is Cardinal Utility?
Cardinal utility is the quantitative measurement of consumer satisfaction. It uses a unit “util” that represents psychological satisfaction through numbers. This allows for mathematical calculations. Unlike ordinal utility, cardinal utility focuses on the consumption of one product at a time.
Assumptions of cardinal utility includes:
- The consumer rationally seeks to maximize satisfaction from their limited disposable income.
- The utility of each product or service is measurable.
- If you use the monetary unit to measure utility, it has to be constant.
- Utility diminishes as a person consumes a commodity in successive units.
Example of Cardinal Utility
Assigning utils may vary per person. For example, you consider whether you should buy a steak or a fish fillet. Based on your preference, you give the steak 10 utils. Meanwhile, you assign seven utils to the fish. Your cardinal utility is denoting that steak is the option that will give you greater satisfaction.
It is important to note that it is possible for utils to decrease as you consume more. If your steak yields 10 utils, it is possible its value will lessen as you eat more, begin to feel full and aren’t enjoying the steak as much as you did at the start.
What Is Ordinal Utility?
Ordinal utility, on the other hand, is qualitative. It is based on the following assumptions:
- Consumers are rational. They aim to maximize total utility based on the limited income at their disposal and the prices of the products or services.
- The utility of each product is not measurable by numbers. Instead, they can be ranked based on the order of preference.
- Consumers are consistent with their choices.
- Consumers are willing to exchange between two goods to maintain the level of satisfaction.
- Total utility is based on the number of commodities they consume. That means it adds different utilities.
- Consumers would always opt for a larger bundle of products or services over a smaller bundle with the same items.
Example of Ordinal Utility
Generally, ordinal utility focuses on a person's preference. For example, imagine you are given three options at a café. These include coffee, milk and tea. Based on what you like, you rank the three items with coffee as the one you prefer the most and tea as your last choice. That means your ranking order is coffee > milk > tea. This order reflects your preference. However, it does not show how much you like coffee more than milk and tea.
Understanding Total and Marginal Utility
There are two ways to view utility. First, there is total utility. It refers to the sum of a person’s satisfaction from consuming all units of a certain commodity. The second one is marginal utility, wherein additional utility is gained as a person consumes additional units of a product or service.
What Is Total Utility?
Total utility is the aggregate amount of all utilities a person gained from consuming a certain amount of a product or service within their income level or budget constraint.
The total utility changes as consumption of the same product increases. The first unit consumed has the highest utility. The second unit has a lower utility than the first, and so on. That means the growth in the total utility becomes less as an additional unit is consumed.
How to Calculate Total Utility
Total utility is the summation of all utilities. It is represented in utils.
In most cases, economists evaluate utils across a spectrum. This way, they get a comparative analysis of util amounts or how much satisfaction is gained from every additional unit. It is important to assign a base value for utils when determining total utility.
The formula is simple. You determine the total based on the numerical value assigned for each.
Example of Total Utility
To better understand total utility, here is an example:
Mark is hungry, so he orders a pepperoni pizza. Under the concept of total utility, it is assumed that Mark’s satisfaction level varies for each slice he eats.
The first slice will give him the highest level of satisfaction, given that he’s hungry and pepperoni is his favorite type of pizza. The second slice has lower utility than the first. By the third slice, he’s experiencing an even lower utility and satisfaction than the second. This situation happens because Mark’s appetite and desire for the pizza decreases as he consumes each slice.
The table and graph below represent the total utility Mark experiences from eating the pizza. The utility utils increase, while the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility shows that with each additional piece of pizza, Mark’s appetite and desire for more food decreases.
No. of Pizza Slices | Total Utilities |
---|---|
0 Slice | 0 utils |
1 Slice | 10 utils |
2 Slices | 19 utils |
3 Slices | 27 utils |
4 Slices | 34 utils |
Using the data from the table above, we can plot the total utility of Mark's pizza experience on a graph. Take a look at the graph below and compare it with the table above.
What Is Marginal Utility?
Marginal utility represents the level of fulfillment a person gets as they consume more units of the same product or service. It reflects the changes in the perceived satisfaction of a consumer for every additional unit. Understanding marginal utility helps assess the change in a person's perception of a commodity.
The best way to understand marginal and total utility is through the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility. It states that additional satisfaction decreases as you consume more of a single product or service.
How to Calculate Marginal Utility
The formula to calculate marginal utility can be defined as the change in total utility divided by the change in units of the commodity.
It can be represented as:
Example of Marginal Utility
Using the example of Mark and his pizza, we can make the observation that despite the increase in total utility, the increase in utils lessens as Mark eats more slices of pizza.
Marginal utility can be visualized as:
Number of Pizza Slices | Total Utility | Marginal Utility |
---|---|---|
0 Slice | 0 utils | -- |
1 Slice | 10 utils | -- |
2 Slices | 19 utils | 9 utils |
3 Slices | 27 utils | 8 utils |
4 Slices | 34 utils | 7 utils |
Notice how marginal utility lessens as Mark consumes more pizza slices. That is because a consumer, once their needs or wants are met, gets the greatest level of satisfaction from the first unit of the product.
To calculate marginal utility:
1st slice: (10 - 0) / (1 - 0) = 10
2nd slice: (19 - 10) / (2 - 1) = 9
3rd slice: (27 -19) / (3 - 2) = 8
4th slice: (34 – 17) / (4 - 3) = 7
How to Maximize Utility: A Rule for Utility Maximization
The concept of utility maximization can be described as a strategy used to achieve the highest level of fulfillment from their decision. To determine the combination of products or services that will help maximize utility, compare the marginal utility of the options. Then, find an alternative that offers the highest total utility within the budget constraints. The rule for utility maximization calculates how many units of an item a consumer will purchase. It relies on the idea that people tend to buy what they want.
Utility maximization can be best understood through the following formula:
The formula shows that every dollar spent on a product or service should bring the same amount of marginal utility. This way, the consumer has spent their money well and can remain within the budget they created and maintain.
For example, Bart wants to buy meat at the grocery store. He has a $20 budget and is choosing between a pound of beef and a pound of pork. He gives beef 10 utils and pork eight utils. A pound of beef costs $10, while a pound of pork costs $5.In this situation, for Bart to maximize his budget and his total utility in his purchases, we will have to take a closer look at each meat.
Take a look at the two tables below of each of the meat.
Maximize Utility for Beef
Qty of Beef | Total Utility | Marginal Utility | MU / Price |
---|---|---|---|
1 Pound | 10 utils | 10 utils | 10/$10 = 1 |
2 Pounds | 17 utils | 7 utils | 7/$10 = 0.7 |
3 Pounds | 21 utils | 4 utils | 4/$10 = 0.4 |
4 Pounds | 22 utils | 1 utils | 4/$10 = 0.1 |
Maximize Utility for Pork
Qty of Pork | Total Utility | Marginal Utility | MU / Price |
---|---|---|---|
1 Pound | 8 utils | 8 utils | 8/$5 = 1.6 |
2 Pounds | 14 utils | 6 utils | 6/$5 = 1.2 |
3 Pounds | 18 utils | 4 utils | 4/$5 = 0.8 |
4 Pounds | 20 utils | 2 utils | 4/$5 = 0.4 |
From the two tables above, Bart’s budget allows him to purchase both beef and pork or purchase only one type of meat. For example, Bart can purchase 2 pounds of beef for $20, which gives him 17 utils, or 4 pounds of pork at $20, giving him 20 utils.
If Bart wants to maximize his utility, he will buy both types of meat until he reaches his budget. His best option is 1 pound of beef for $10 at 10 utils and 2 pounds of pork for $10 at 14 utils for a total of $20 at 24 utils.
How does the concept of utility impacts markets or the economy in general? Can you provide examples?
As a simple example, suppose we are interested in the ice cream market and are trying to explain various patterns in how the price of ice cream changes over time and across locations. We can say the average consumer gains more utility from eating ice cream on a hot day than on a cold day. We don't need to necessarily know how much more or the degree to which each consumer feels that way. We can bypass that and focus on trying to understand why that translates into consumers willing to pay more for ice cream in the summer, how ice cream prices differ in warmer areas compared to colder ones, and so forth.
Another fact about utility is that people make purchasing decisions based on their expected utility from buying and consuming something. Their actual utility comes after they make the purchase. That means there can be a difference between the utility they thought they would get when they made the purchase and what they actually received. That can be an explanation for phenomena we see in consumer behavior, such as buyer's remorse. A consumer expected higher utility than what they actually ended up receiving. Markets are complex collections of economic agents interacting and making decisions.
The concept of utility allows us to simplify some of that complex economic behavior in order to focus on the behavior or results we are interested in explaining. To the extent that we can think of the economy in general as a collection of markets made up of consumers trying to maximize their utility while businesses try to maximize their profits, the concept of utility can even be useful for understanding some macroeconomic behavior as well.
As a simple example, suppose we are interested in the ice cream market and are trying to explain various patterns in how the price of ice cream changes over time and across locations. We can say the average consumer gains more utility from eating ice cream on a hot day than on a cold day. We don't need to necessarily know how much more or the degree to which each consumer feels that way. We can bypass that and focus on trying to understand why that translates into consumers willing to pay more for ice cream in the summer, how ice cream prices differ in warmer areas compared to colder ones, and so forth.
Another fact about utility is that people make purchasing decisions based on their expected utility from buying and consuming something. Their actual utility comes after they make the purchase. That means there can be a difference between the utility they thought they would get when they made the purchase and what they actually received. That can be an explanation for phenomena we see in consumer behavior, such as buyer's remorse. A consumer expected higher utility than what they actually ended up receiving. Markets are complex collections of economic agents interacting and making decisions.
The concept of utility allows us to simplify some of that complex economic behavior in order to focus on the behavior or results we are interested in explaining. To the extent that we can think of the economy in general as a collection of markets made up of consumers trying to maximize their utility while businesses try to maximize their profits, the concept of utility can even be useful for understanding some macroeconomic behavior as well.
Utility does not impact markets or the economy. Specifying a particular utility function, however, does determine the form of the equilibrium that is being described, which may or may not be a good description of the economy in the area of interest by the author specifying the utility function. Different models are designed to explain what we see in the economy. Different utility functions are experimented with in the process to see how they affect the outcome (equilibrium).
The most common utility function in macroeconomics simply assumes that the household gets utility from consuming goods and time (leisure). In a sense, only goods (matter) and time exist in the world we live in, so this gives a broad framework used worldwide for many years in macroeconomics.
Have a question?
Ask a question, it’s free
Ask an expertUtility FAQs
In economics, utility is the satisfaction level an individual gets from buying and using a product or service. Utility is used to explain how consumers make purchase decisions based on the perceived utility of a commodity. It is divided into two categories, total and marginal, and can be measured through utils or the units of satisfaction.
Given that utility is the measurement of satisfaction a person receives by consuming a product or service, analyzing utility will give insight on consumer preferences. It allows you to predict buyer action and preference, and it may also affect consumer demand and market movements.
Consumer behavior refers to how individuals or groups make purchase decisions. There are various factors affecting a consumer's decision. One of these is utility. The concept of utility states that people tend to choose products or services that provide the highest level of satisfaction at a price that is within their budget.
Expert Insights
Learning about utility and its role in the economy can be a bit difficult. MoneyGeek spoke with an industry expert and an academic to provide expert insight on utility in economics.
- What is the best way to understand the role of utility in economics?
- How does the concept of utility impacts markets or the economy in general? Can you provide examples?
Related Content
Utility is only one aspect affecting the economy. MoneyGeek has researched other financial and economic concepts and created a variety of guides to help you make better financial choices.
- What Your “Treat Yourself” Habits Says About You and How to Overcome Them: Learn more about the psychology behind the “treat yourself” concept and find tips on how you can manage splurges and practice better spending habits.
- Financial Steps for Each Decade: Explore the financial steps you should take in every decade of your life. Use this as a guide to adjust your money habits to build and maintain a healthy financial portfolio.
- The Guide to Budgeting: Creating a budget plan can be tough. Learn how to get started with budgeting tips, examples, savings goals and strategies to improve your spending habits.
- Financial Literacy Handbook: While it is important to make smart financial decisions, it can be challenging. Explore money management tips and resources to help you understand where you should focus to immediately begin improving your financial literacy skills.
- Guide to Debt Reduction: Are you worried about debt? Review various strategies that can help you reduce your debts and work best for your situation.
About Nathan Paulus
Nathan Paulus is the Head of Content Marketing at MoneyGeek, with nearly 10 years of experience researching and creating content related to personal finance and financial literacy.
Paulus has a bachelor's degree in English from the University of St. Thomas, Houston. He enjoys helping people from all walks of life build stronger financial foundations.
sources
- Bernoulli, D. "Exposition of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk." Accessed September 26, 2024.
- Mulando, L. "Cardinal and Ordinal Approaches to Consumer's Behavior." Accessed September 26, 2024.
- Oregon State University. "Module 2 Utility and Utility Functions." Accessed September 26, 2024.
- University of Minnesota. "Principles of Economics: 7.1 The Concept of Utility." Accessed September 26, 2024.
- University of Minnesota. "Principles of Economics: 7.2 Utility Maximization and Demand." Accessed September 26, 2024.